Pardon Our Interruption

As you were browsing something about your browser made us think you were a bot. There are a few reasons this might happen:

  • You've disabled JavaScript in your web browser.
  • You're a power user moving through this website with super-human speed.
  • You've disabled cookies in your web browser.
  • A third-party browser plugin, such as Ghostery or NoScript, is preventing JavaScript from running. Additional information is available in this support article .

To regain access, please make sure that cookies and JavaScript are enabled before reloading the page.

Locus Assignments

Assignment on Organizational Structure and Culture

Assignment on Organizational Structure Culture

Introduction          

Organizational structure and culture is the base of any organization. The structures define the rules and policies which develops the culture of the organization. For achieving success, the structure and culture must be very open, innovative and creative in which the employees can easily adjust and gain satisfaction from the work environment. In this Assignment on Organizational Structure Culture, the relationship, comparison between the structure and culture will be discussed. Along with the culture, the different styles of leadership and management approaches will be explained.

1.1 Compare and contrast the structure and culture of the organization.

Organizational structure refers to the norms, rules, policies formed by the company to achieve the objectives. Organizational Culture includes the value, behaviour and attitudes of the employees. Both of these are equally important for the success of the organization. Every organization has a different structures and culture depending upon the size, nature and scale of operations etc.

Difference between Tall, flat and hierarchical Structure

1. Meaning

It is also known as tall structure. It comprises of various levels in the hierarchy

Where the managers are very less signifies that the company had wide hierarchical level and thus the structure is flat

2. Span of control

Narrow

Wide

3. Formal & informal relations

The manager share a informal relation with his sub-ordinates

Formal relations as the no. of subordinates are more.

4. Coordination level

Great level of co-ordination is followed in tall structure

Co-ordination level is low

5. Cost

This is costly because large no. of managers are available

Less costly as the no. of managers are few

6. Decision Making

Slow decision making process

Fast decision making process

7. Communication

Due to many levels, the communication can be delayed or changed in the process

Due to less levels of management, the communication is fast and clear

8. Example

Tesco Plc

Software Mill and Amazon.com

Culture in flat and Hierarchiacal/ tall structure

 

           

Power is centralized means the decision making authority is in the hands of few employees

 

These cultures are purely based on rules.

Specials group are formed to deal with any particular situation or issue. Source of power is not defined

It is a collection of different people who works for the same organization

Employees are judged by their levels of achievement

Employees are aware about their duties and power.

These team are highly productive

Every employee feels themselves as superior to other

Quick decision making lead to disasters in the company

Decision making is very slow

Decision making is according to the importance of situation. It can be fast or slow

Individual decision making

Ex- RBS and Lehman Brothers

 

 

Matrix organizations

1.2 Relationship between an organisation’s structure and culture

Organizational structure and culture are interdependent. An organizational structure defines the attitude, policies, framework, strategies and moral values which ultimately creates the work/ organizational culture.

For example- if an organization follows a strict hierarchy and the decision making authority is fixed/ allotted to the top management, then there will be lack of freedom and employee involvement and the culture will be less effective and rigid. But if the organization structure is decentralized which means the authority, responsibility and decision making power is shared with the employees at all levels, the culture will be more innovative, interesting, accountable and independent.

The way, an organization distributes authority and responsibility, defines its employees behaviour. These decisions of structure form the organizational culture. Organizational structure is the method by which a company manages its operations and hierarchy of authority. It defines the roles, communication channels, line of authority, rules etc. within the company. Mostly the organizational structure makes a form of pyramid where the top management is at the top of pyramid structure which comprises of president or CEO.

The pyramid shows the different level of management which may differ company to company depending upon the objectives of different organizations. Top management has the most powerful authority. It controls the functioning of all the organization. In the same way, employees at different level have different authority and power levels to carry out the tasks assigned to them. The pyramid goes in downward direction i.e., from top to lower level of management.  

For example: If the president wants to assign the decision making authority to someone else, then that would be vice-president as per the structure of the organization. It shows that the vice-president has a direct line of authority after the president and now all the people will report to him, at that time he will possess the greatest power and authority (OC&OS. n.d.).

The organizational structure and culture has a vast impact on the performance level of the employees. If the organizational structure and culture is rigid or centralized, the performance of the employees will be average and normal not excellent because the rigid structure do not allow freedom and employees involvement in the business operation which de-motivates employees and they are not able to perform well. On the other hand, the decentralised structure allows the employees to communicate and participate in the business and decision making process which highly motivates them to perform better and stay loyal to the organization. Such employees show positive improvement, innovation and excellence in their assigned jobs.

1.3  Discuss the factors which influence the behavior of an individual at work focusing of personality, traits and   its usefulness in understanding self and others

Personality: It refers to the combination of different qualities which forms a person’s character or nature. It also defines the behaviour of people. The manager must study the personality traits/ features of an individual during the recruiting process. Because a person with a great personality can be an asset and the person with bad or negative personality can be burden for the organization (Prevedouros, 1990).

Every individual has a distinctive personality due to which he responds differently to a situation as compared to others. The personality affects the behaviour of a person. In this task, we’ll discuss the OCEAN model of personality trait also known as Big Five Personality Test.

Traits of the Big Five personality test

The HR manager uses the big five personality dimension to help the employees and influence their behaviour at the workplace. These 5 dimensions make the overall personality of an individual. These five traits are:

1. Openness: First dimension or area is openness. The person who is eager to learn new things and wants to have different experiences in life comes under the high scoring category in openness. It includes the qualities of being innovative, creative and imaginative.

2. Conscientiousness: People who have high degree of vigilance are more reliable as compared to the people who are easy going and unorganized. It includes various traits like being vigilant, organised and focused.

3. Extraversion: Refers to the people who are interactive and open with the other people. Such people are talkative, enthusiastic and energetic. These people are easy to work with and know how to behave and work within a team.

4. Agreeableness: This dimension includes the traits of being kind, affectionate and trustworthy. The people having this trait are more co-operative, friendly and kind.

5. Neuroticism: People having high degree of this trait could experience sadness, anxiety, mood swings, instable etc. These dimensions are associated with the emotional stability.

All these five dimensions constitute a complete personality of an individual and affect its behaviour at the workplace or anywhere.

2.1 Compare leadership styles in different organizations.

Leaders are the one who have the quality to influence the behaviour of other person. A manager must possess the leadership quality to handle different situations, to motivate employees, control the activities, monitoring the performance guiding the employees. There are different types of leadership styles which are adopted by the organization. The leadership style signifies the nature of the leader and the way he carries out the leadership within the organization. In this question I have taken the example of Microsoft’s CEO Mr. Satya Nadella. The Microsoft is led by a calm, patient, steady and composed CEO. Satya nadella’s follows Participative/ collaborative leadership style (KAY, 2015).

Leadership styles:

Autocratic Style :  It is also known as authoritarian/leader centred style; it clearly reflects that there is division between leaders and workers. The authority is centralized i.e., the decision is taken by the leader and employees are not involved in the decision making process .  This style assesses strict control on the employees and allots the work load to the employees. The employees has to follows the rules and order led by the leader. This style allows quick decision making and better results can be obtained in the time of crisis or emergency. The leaders following this leadership style are a bit traditional in their approach and displays less innovations and creativity. The employees feel disconnected with such kind of leader and do not stay in the organization in the long run.  Example: This style was followed by the ex CEO of Microsoft- Steve Ballmer.

Participative Leadership:   Also called collaborative leadership, this style is completely opposite of autocratic style. In this style, the decision making process is decentralized which means the employees are involved in the decision making. The leader allocates authority to his subordinates. Though he makes the final decision but the feedbacks, views, ideas of employees are considered before making the decision. It focuses on both the people and the work. This leadership style improves the relationship between the leader and the sub ordinate and improves the job satisfaction of the employees. It helps in reducing the labour turnover ratio and increases the decision quality. Example- Satya Nadella (CEO) - Microsoft follows this leadership style.

Free-rein Leadership: This style, also called laissez-faire leadership, is generally considered the least effective option. This style offers complete freedom to the employees. The entire decision making is allocated to the employees. The leader do not interfere in the decision making process, he only guide them. This style gives full scope of growth and helps the employees in developing their independent personalities. But this style has some disadvantages as well like the line of authority becomes confusing. It has less accountability on the part of employees and mostly misused by the employees (Chand, n.d.).

2.2 Explain how organizational theory underpins the practice of management.

Organizational theory and management theory is used in many aspects of a working business. Many people follow the theory to become better at their jobs or more successful in life. Organizational theory, if practically executed, can be very important as it can affect the overall performance of the organization. It studies the relation of various organizations with the environment they are operating in. Organizational structure, culture, leadership styles, approaches of management and motivational theories were developed long before but they are constantly evolving to help the managers to understand the business environment , and carry out the business activity to achieve the targets for the organization.

The management theory is a collection of different ideas, innovations and policies created to help the managers in carrying out the day to day activities. The hypothesis of administration helps managers to know and comprehend the objectives of the association; it helps them in arranging work keeping in mind the end goal to accomplish these objectives in the best and proficient way; it helps them to comprehend what propels individuals and it demonstrates to them ways best practices to do it (Currie & Goldin, 2012).

A manger has to play various roles within the organization. It means that the manager constantly switches to different roles as per the requirement.  Henry Mintzberg, a professor and management expert recognized these changes and categorised all the roles under three main categories:

1. Interpersonal Category

This category has 3 roles played by the manager in order to provide different ideas and information:

Figurehead: The manager has various social, legal, motivational responsibilities. He is known as the inspiration for the employees and has high degree of authority.

Leader: He is the head of his team or department. The leader has to train, motivate, interact and encourage his team or subordinates.

Liaison: The manager has to maintain contacts with the internal and external people. He must have the ability to create and maintain a network on behalf of the organization.

2. Informational Category

Monitor: He has the responsibility to monitor the performance, evaluate the training programs, and maintain a regular report, and personal contact with all the employees. He also has to ensure the well being of his team.

Spokesperson: The manger is also the spokesperson to the external sources or contacts. He has to transfer the information and goals to all the outside sources and conduct meetings and conferences.

Disseminator: Person who can communicate all the necessary information within the organization. Hence, a manger also plays a role of disseminator. He passes the decisions, reports and other necessary information to its subordinates.

3. Decisional Category

Entrepreneur: The manager has to identify new ideas and innovations to start new projects and he has to improve the existing projects as well.

Disturbance handler: The manager has to resolve the issues and conflicts arise within the organization. He also has to identify the corrective actions or the solutions of the problems.

Resource allocator: He has to identify the area where the resources should be allocated. The manger has to identify, plan, arrange and allocate the resources at the required levels or departments within the organization.

Negotiator: He participates in the debates and discussions to protect the business. He has to negotiate within the team or department of the organization (MAW Editor, 2015).

2.3 Evaluate the different approaches to management used by different organizations

The management approaches can be divided into three main groups: Classical approach, Neo- classical approach and the Modern approach.

Classical Approaches consists of:

  • scientific management approach;
  • classical administration approach;
  • bureaucratic approach;

Scientific Management Approach was developed by the theorist F. W. Taylor. According to him, the productivity can be maximises by simplifying the jobs. He also says that the manager and the workers must co operate with each other to accomplish the target easily and effectively. This was a very new concept as earlier the managers were not very involved with the workers. He also emphasises that salary must be according to the work done to encourage the hard workers and eliminate the lazy workers from the organization (Eyre, n.d.)

Classical Administration Approach was developed by Henry Fayol. His approach focuses on the human aspect of the employees. His main focus was to train the employees instead of individual efficiency. He developed 14 principles of management which defines the way an organization should operate. It states the importance of discipline, unity in direction, importance of one boss, benefits of team work, proper authority and responsibility, delegating of work to the subordinates and so on. He was more concerned towards the improvement in managerial practices to increase the efficiency of the employees

Bureaucratic Approach was developed by Max Weber (1864-1920).

His theory explains that there must be proper rules and regulation to be followed by the organization. He emphasised on the importance of selection of workers on the basis of skills and qualification and the also work must be assigned according to the skills of the workers. The organizational structure must be formed in such a way that the communication flow can be very smooth from the top to lower management. Example- His approach is suitable for the government organizations. (Schiller, 2008).

Neo- classical Approach includes

  • Human Relation Approach.

Human Relation Approach was developed by Elton Mayo. As the name suggest the theory focuses on the human aspects. His theory says that if the manager takes care of the employees and co operates with them, then the employees will be highly motivated. When the manager shows concern towards his employees, he gains their loyalty and commitment. His work also defines the importance of team work and how it can be helpful in achieving the targets and objectives for the organization.

Modern Approaches includes:

  • System Approach
  • Contingency Approach

System Approach: This theory explains that in any organization, all the things are inter related dependent on each other. The importance was given towards the usefulness of the complete system (including systems and sub systems). This theory was useful for the management to achieve the success as it defines the organization as an open system. Open system means system which were thoroughly studied, discussed and examined. All the factors of organization are used in this which reflects the problems, issues or success of the organization as a whole.

Contingency Approach is also known as situational approach. It was developed by J.W. Lorsch and P.R. Lawrence. This theory prepares the organization for the future. It says that the policies, strategies of the organization must respond to change in the internal or external environment . It also focuses on the importance of forecasting. The organizations must oversee and anticipate the future requirement and should be ready to face them. they should also have sufficient employees to meet the future requirement and work more in the time of emergency for the organization (Chand, n.d.).

Get assignment help from full time dedicated experts of Locus assignments.

Call us: +44 – 7497 786 317 Email: [email protected]

BTEC HND Assignment Experts

Organizational behaviour reflects how an organization is functioning. It includes the structure and culture which determine the future of the company. The success of any organization is largely depends upon its culture which can retain or lose the employees. The employees will be loyal to the organization where the culture is innovative and encouraging; the leader is co operative and helpful and all the people work together to achieve the common goals for the success of the organization. In the above report all the important aspects of an organization like culture, structure, leadership style, management approaches etc were discussed with the help of an example of the company Microsoft.

Akrani, G. (2011). Difference between Tall and Flat Organisation Structure. [Online]. Available from: http://kalyan-city.blogspot.com/2011/06/difference-between-tall-and-flat.html Chand, S. (n.d.). Styles of Leadership: Autocratic, Democratic and Free Rein Style. [Online]. Available from: http://www.yourarticlelibrary.com/leadership/3-styles-of-leadership-autocratic-democratic-and-free-rein-style/28002/ Chand, S. (n.d.). Modern Management Theory. [Online]. Available from: http://www.yourarticlelibrary.com/management/modern-management-theory-quantitative-system-and-contingency-approaches-to-management/25621/

Delivery in day(s): 3

  • Number of views: 572
  • Unit: Unit 12 Organisational Behaviour
  • Level: level 4 in business

Share this Solution

facebook

Other Assignments

Computing Skills Assignment Help

Computing Skills Assignment Help

Delivery in day(s): 5

Organisational Behaviour Assignment Help

Organisational Behaviour Assignment Help

Business Law Assignment

Business Law Assignment

Delivery in day(s): 4

International Management Assignment Help

International Management Assignment Help

Business Law Assignment Help

Business Law Assignment Help

Related solutions.

Unit 12 organizational Structure and Culture Assignment

Unit 12 organizational Structure and Culture Assignment

Assignment on Organizational Structure Culture

Unit 12 Leadership Style Assignment Solution

Organizational Behaviour Assignment

Organizational Behaviour Assignment

Organisation and Behaviour Assignment - British Airways

Unit 3 Organisation and Behaviour Assignment - British Airways

Organisations and Behaviour Assignment Solution McDonald

Unit 3 Organisations and Behaviour Assignment Solution- McDonald

  • Unit 1 Business and Business Environment
  • Unit 1 Business Skills for e-Commerce
  • Unit 1 Communicating in HSC Organisations
  • Unit 1 The Contemporary Hospitality Industry
  • Unit 1 The Travel and Tourism Sector

Other Solutions

Unit 6 Business Decision Making Assignment Help

Unit 6 Business Decision Making Assignment Help

Business Strategy Assignment Solutions

Business Strategy Assignment Solutions

Managing Business Activities to Achieve Results Assignment Help

Managing Business Activities to Achieve Results Assignment Help

External Business Environment Assignment Help

External Business Environment Assignment Help

Contemporary Issues in Travel and Tourism Assignment Help

Contemporary Issues in Travel and Tourism Assignment Help

Business Environment Assignment - British Airways

Business Environment Assignment - British Airways

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Provide details on what you need help with along with a budget and time limit. Questions are posted anonymously and can be made 100% private.

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Studypool matches you to the best tutor to help you with your question. Our tutors are highly qualified and vetted.

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Your matched tutor provides personalized help according to your question details. Payment is made only after you have completed your 1-on-1 session and are satisfied with your session.

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  • Homework Q&A
  • Become a Tutor

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

All Subjects

Mathematics

Programming

Health & Medical

Engineering

Computer Science

Foreign Languages

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Access over 35 million academic & study documents

1 3 journal organizational structure culture.

Sign up to view the full document!

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

24/7 Study Help

Stuck on a study question? Our verified tutors can answer all questions, from basic  math  to advanced rocket science !

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Similar Documents

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

working on a study question?

Studypool, Inc., Tutoring, Mountain View, CA

Studypool is powered by Microtutoring TM

Copyright © 2024. Studypool Inc.

Studypool is not sponsored or endorsed by any college or university.

Ongoing Conversations

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Access over 35 million study documents through the notebank

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Get on-demand Q&A study help from verified tutors

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Read 1000s of rich book guides covering popular titles

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Sign up with Google

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

Sign up with Facebook

Already have an account? Login

Login with Google

Login with Facebook

Don't have an account? Sign Up

Discount Offer

  • Assignments
  • Dissertations
  • Research Proposal
  • Report Writing
  • Literature Review
  • CDR Writing
  • Resume Writing
  • Engineering
  • IT & Computer Science
  • Value Added Services
  • Plagiarism Check
  • Proofreading & Editing
  • Expert Consultation
  • Live Session 1-On-1

Quality Check

  • By University
  • By Subject Codes
  • Free Samples
  • Reviews 4.5/5
  • Help & Support
  • Certified Experts
  • Our Policies
  • Ask your Question
  • Request Callback
  • Get $50 Off
  • Get 500 Words Free
  • Premium Membership

Quick Searches

  • Samples - e.g. Management Assignment Samples
  • Services - e.g. MATLAB Assignment Help
  • Support : FAQs , Policies, Ordering Support

Organizational Culture And Structure

Please Wait

Fetching Result....

  • Internal Code :
  • Subject Code :
  • University :
  • Subject Name:

No Worries! Get Instant Solution to your Assignment Questions

Upload your question file, share your details with subject experts for instant solution.

  • Algeria (+213)
  • Antigua and barbuda (+1268)
  • Australia (+61)
  • Austria (+43)
  • Azerbaijan (+994)
  • Bahrain (+973)
  • Bangladesh (+880)
  • Canada (+1)
  • China (+86)
  • Congo (+243)
  • Cyprus (+357)
  • Europe (+3)
  • France (+33)
  • Germany (+49)
  • Ghana (+233)
  • Greece (+30)
  • Hong kong (+8)
  • Hungary (+36)
  • India (+91)
  • Indonesia (+62)
  • Iran (islamic republic of) (+98)
  • Ireland (+353)
  • Jamaica (+1)
  • Japan (+82)
  • Jordan (+962)
  • Kazakhstan (+7)
  • Kenya (+254)
  • Kuwait (+965)
  • Latvia (+371)
  • Lesotho (+266)
  • Malaysia (+60)
  • Maldives (+960)
  • Malta (+356)
  • Mauritius (+230)
  • Myanmar (+95)
  • Namibia (+264)
  • Nepal (+977)
  • Netherlands (+31)
  • New zealand (+64)
  • Nigeria (+234)
  • Norway (+47)
  • Oman (+968)
  • Pakistan (+92)
  • Papua new guinea (+675)
  • Philippines (+63)
  • Poland (+48)
  • Qatar (+974)
  • Saudi arabia (+966)
  • Singapore (+65)
  • Somalia (+252)
  • South africa (+27)
  • South korea (+82)
  • Spain (+34)
  • Sri lanka (+94)
  • Sweden (+46)
  • Switzerland (+41)
  • Taiwan (+886)
  • Thailand (+66)
  • Turkey (+90)
  • Uganda (+256)
  • Ukraine (+380)
  • United arab emirates (+971)
  • United kingdom (+44)
  • United states america (+1)
  • Uzbekistan (+998)
  • Vietnam (+84)
  • Yemen (+967)
  • Zambia (+260)
  • Zimbabwe (+263)

Get Quote in 5 Minutes*

1,212,718 Orders

4.9/5 Rating

5,063 Experts

Side Banner Ad

  • 21 Step Quality Check
  • 2000+ Ph.D Experts
  • Live Expert Sessions
  • Dedicated App
  • Earn while you Learn with us
  • Confidentiality Agreement
  • Money Back Guarantee
  • Customer Feedback

Just Pay for your Assignment

Turnitin Report

Proofreading and Editing

Consultation with Expert

Live Session 1-on-1

  • Let's Start

Other Subjects

Bonanza Offer Get 40% Off * on your assignment today

Searching across 1 Million Samples...

Doing your Assignment with our samples is simple, take Expert assistance to ensure HD Grades. Here you Go....

Today's Special Get Upto 50% OFF *

TrustPilot Reviews

Select Coupon

  • Search Menu
  • Sign in through your institution
  • Browse content in A - General Economics and Teaching
  • Browse content in A1 - General Economics
  • A12 - Relation of Economics to Other Disciplines
  • A14 - Sociology of Economics
  • Browse content in C - Mathematical and Quantitative Methods
  • Browse content in C1 - Econometric and Statistical Methods and Methodology: General
  • C11 - Bayesian Analysis: General
  • C13 - Estimation: General
  • Browse content in C2 - Single Equation Models; Single Variables
  • C21 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions
  • C23 - Panel Data Models; Spatio-temporal Models
  • Browse content in C3 - Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models; Multiple Variables
  • C31 - Cross-Sectional Models; Spatial Models; Treatment Effect Models; Quantile Regressions; Social Interaction Models
  • Browse content in C4 - Econometric and Statistical Methods: Special Topics
  • C44 - Operations Research; Statistical Decision Theory
  • Browse content in C6 - Mathematical Methods; Programming Models; Mathematical and Simulation Modeling
  • C63 - Computational Techniques; Simulation Modeling
  • Browse content in C7 - Game Theory and Bargaining Theory
  • C70 - General
  • C72 - Noncooperative Games
  • C73 - Stochastic and Dynamic Games; Evolutionary Games; Repeated Games
  • C78 - Bargaining Theory; Matching Theory
  • Browse content in C8 - Data Collection and Data Estimation Methodology; Computer Programs
  • C81 - Methodology for Collecting, Estimating, and Organizing Microeconomic Data; Data Access
  • Browse content in C9 - Design of Experiments
  • C91 - Laboratory, Individual Behavior
  • C92 - Laboratory, Group Behavior
  • C93 - Field Experiments
  • Browse content in D - Microeconomics
  • Browse content in D0 - General
  • D02 - Institutions: Design, Formation, Operations, and Impact
  • D03 - Behavioral Microeconomics: Underlying Principles
  • Browse content in D1 - Household Behavior and Family Economics
  • D10 - General
  • D13 - Household Production and Intrahousehold Allocation
  • D14 - Household Saving; Personal Finance
  • D18 - Consumer Protection
  • Browse content in D2 - Production and Organizations
  • D20 - General
  • D21 - Firm Behavior: Theory
  • D22 - Firm Behavior: Empirical Analysis
  • D23 - Organizational Behavior; Transaction Costs; Property Rights
  • D24 - Production; Cost; Capital; Capital, Total Factor, and Multifactor Productivity; Capacity
  • Browse content in D3 - Distribution
  • D30 - General
  • Browse content in D4 - Market Structure, Pricing, and Design
  • D44 - Auctions
  • Browse content in D6 - Welfare Economics
  • D62 - Externalities
  • D63 - Equity, Justice, Inequality, and Other Normative Criteria and Measurement
  • Browse content in D7 - Analysis of Collective Decision-Making
  • D71 - Social Choice; Clubs; Committees; Associations
  • D72 - Political Processes: Rent-seeking, Lobbying, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior
  • D73 - Bureaucracy; Administrative Processes in Public Organizations; Corruption
  • D74 - Conflict; Conflict Resolution; Alliances; Revolutions
  • D78 - Positive Analysis of Policy Formulation and Implementation
  • D79 - Other
  • Browse content in D8 - Information, Knowledge, and Uncertainty
  • D81 - Criteria for Decision-Making under Risk and Uncertainty
  • D82 - Asymmetric and Private Information; Mechanism Design
  • D83 - Search; Learning; Information and Knowledge; Communication; Belief; Unawareness
  • D85 - Network Formation and Analysis: Theory
  • D86 - Economics of Contract: Theory
  • D9 - Micro-Based Behavioral Economics
  • Browse content in E - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Browse content in E2 - Consumption, Saving, Production, Investment, Labor Markets, and Informal Economy
  • E24 - Employment; Unemployment; Wages; Intergenerational Income Distribution; Aggregate Human Capital; Aggregate Labor Productivity
  • E26 - Informal Economy; Underground Economy
  • Browse content in F - International Economics
  • Browse content in F1 - Trade
  • F10 - General
  • F13 - Trade Policy; International Trade Organizations
  • F15 - Economic Integration
  • Browse content in F5 - International Relations, National Security, and International Political Economy
  • F50 - General
  • F51 - International Conflicts; Negotiations; Sanctions
  • Browse content in G - Financial Economics
  • G0 - General
  • Browse content in G2 - Financial Institutions and Services
  • G24 - Investment Banking; Venture Capital; Brokerage; Ratings and Ratings Agencies
  • G28 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in G3 - Corporate Finance and Governance
  • G30 - General
  • G31 - Capital Budgeting; Fixed Investment and Inventory Studies; Capacity
  • G33 - Bankruptcy; Liquidation
  • G34 - Mergers; Acquisitions; Restructuring; Corporate Governance
  • G38 - Government Policy and Regulation
  • Browse content in H - Public Economics
  • H0 - General
  • Browse content in H1 - Structure and Scope of Government
  • H10 - General
  • H11 - Structure, Scope, and Performance of Government
  • Browse content in H2 - Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H21 - Efficiency; Optimal Taxation
  • H24 - Personal Income and Other Nonbusiness Taxes and Subsidies; includes inheritance and gift taxes
  • H3 - Fiscal Policies and Behavior of Economic Agents
  • Browse content in H4 - Publicly Provided Goods
  • H40 - General
  • H41 - Public Goods
  • H42 - Publicly Provided Private Goods
  • Browse content in H5 - National Government Expenditures and Related Policies
  • H53 - Government Expenditures and Welfare Programs
  • H56 - National Security and War
  • H57 - Procurement
  • Browse content in H7 - State and Local Government; Intergovernmental Relations
  • H70 - General
  • H71 - State and Local Taxation, Subsidies, and Revenue
  • H72 - State and Local Budget and Expenditures
  • H74 - State and Local Borrowing
  • H76 - State and Local Government: Other Expenditure Categories
  • H77 - Intergovernmental Relations; Federalism; Secession
  • Browse content in H8 - Miscellaneous Issues
  • H83 - Public Administration; Public Sector Accounting and Audits
  • Browse content in I - Health, Education, and Welfare
  • Browse content in I1 - Health
  • I11 - Analysis of Health Care Markets
  • I12 - Health Behavior
  • I18 - Government Policy; Regulation; Public Health
  • I2 - Education and Research Institutions
  • Browse content in J - Labor and Demographic Economics
  • Browse content in J1 - Demographic Economics
  • J12 - Marriage; Marital Dissolution; Family Structure; Domestic Abuse
  • J15 - Economics of Minorities, Races, Indigenous Peoples, and Immigrants; Non-labor Discrimination
  • Browse content in J2 - Demand and Supply of Labor
  • J24 - Human Capital; Skills; Occupational Choice; Labor Productivity
  • Browse content in J3 - Wages, Compensation, and Labor Costs
  • J30 - General
  • J31 - Wage Level and Structure; Wage Differentials
  • J33 - Compensation Packages; Payment Methods
  • Browse content in J4 - Particular Labor Markets
  • J41 - Labor Contracts
  • J42 - Monopsony; Segmented Labor Markets
  • J45 - Public Sector Labor Markets
  • Browse content in J5 - Labor-Management Relations, Trade Unions, and Collective Bargaining
  • J50 - General
  • J51 - Trade Unions: Objectives, Structure, and Effects
  • J52 - Dispute Resolution: Strikes, Arbitration, and Mediation; Collective Bargaining
  • Browse content in J6 - Mobility, Unemployment, Vacancies, and Immigrant Workers
  • J61 - Geographic Labor Mobility; Immigrant Workers
  • J62 - Job, Occupational, and Intergenerational Mobility
  • J63 - Turnover; Vacancies; Layoffs
  • Browse content in J8 - Labor Standards: National and International
  • J83 - Workers' Rights
  • Browse content in K - Law and Economics
  • Browse content in K0 - General
  • K00 - General
  • Browse content in K1 - Basic Areas of Law
  • K10 - General
  • K11 - Property Law
  • K12 - Contract Law
  • K13 - Tort Law and Product Liability; Forensic Economics
  • K14 - Criminal Law
  • K16 - Election Law
  • Browse content in K2 - Regulation and Business Law
  • K20 - General
  • K21 - Antitrust Law
  • K22 - Business and Securities Law
  • K23 - Regulated Industries and Administrative Law
  • Browse content in K3 - Other Substantive Areas of Law
  • K31 - Labor Law
  • K32 - Environmental, Health, and Safety Law
  • K33 - International Law
  • K35 - Personal Bankruptcy Law
  • K36 - Family and Personal Law
  • K37 - Immigration Law
  • Browse content in K4 - Legal Procedure, the Legal System, and Illegal Behavior
  • K40 - General
  • K41 - Litigation Process
  • K42 - Illegal Behavior and the Enforcement of Law
  • K49 - Other
  • Browse content in L - Industrial Organization
  • Browse content in L1 - Market Structure, Firm Strategy, and Market Performance
  • L10 - General
  • L12 - Monopoly; Monopolization Strategies
  • L13 - Oligopoly and Other Imperfect Markets
  • L14 - Transactional Relationships; Contracts and Reputation; Networks
  • L15 - Information and Product Quality; Standardization and Compatibility
  • L19 - Other
  • Browse content in L2 - Firm Objectives, Organization, and Behavior
  • L20 - General
  • L21 - Business Objectives of the Firm
  • L22 - Firm Organization and Market Structure
  • L23 - Organization of Production
  • L24 - Contracting Out; Joint Ventures; Technology Licensing
  • L25 - Firm Performance: Size, Diversification, and Scope
  • L26 - Entrepreneurship
  • Browse content in L3 - Nonprofit Organizations and Public Enterprise
  • L31 - Nonprofit Institutions; NGOs; Social Entrepreneurship
  • L33 - Comparison of Public and Private Enterprises and Nonprofit Institutions; Privatization; Contracting Out
  • Browse content in L4 - Antitrust Issues and Policies
  • L40 - General
  • L41 - Monopolization; Horizontal Anticompetitive Practices
  • L42 - Vertical Restraints; Resale Price Maintenance; Quantity Discounts
  • L49 - Other
  • Browse content in L5 - Regulation and Industrial Policy
  • L50 - General
  • L51 - Economics of Regulation
  • Browse content in L6 - Industry Studies: Manufacturing
  • L60 - General
  • Browse content in L7 - Industry Studies: Primary Products and Construction
  • L71 - Mining, Extraction, and Refining: Hydrocarbon Fuels
  • Browse content in L8 - Industry Studies: Services
  • L82 - Entertainment; Media
  • L84 - Personal, Professional, and Business Services
  • L86 - Information and Internet Services; Computer Software
  • Browse content in L9 - Industry Studies: Transportation and Utilities
  • L95 - Gas Utilities; Pipelines; Water Utilities
  • Browse content in M - Business Administration and Business Economics; Marketing; Accounting; Personnel Economics
  • Browse content in M1 - Business Administration
  • M12 - Personnel Management; Executives; Executive Compensation
  • M14 - Corporate Culture; Social Responsibility
  • M15 - IT Management
  • Browse content in M2 - Business Economics
  • M21 - Business Economics
  • Browse content in M4 - Accounting and Auditing
  • M40 - General
  • Browse content in M5 - Personnel Economics
  • M50 - General
  • M51 - Firm Employment Decisions; Promotions
  • M52 - Compensation and Compensation Methods and Their Effects
  • M53 - Training
  • Browse content in N - Economic History
  • Browse content in N1 - Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics; Industrial Structure; Growth; Fluctuations
  • N13 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • N14 - Europe: 1913-
  • N15 - Asia including Middle East
  • Browse content in N2 - Financial Markets and Institutions
  • N24 - Europe: 1913-
  • Browse content in N3 - Labor and Consumers, Demography, Education, Health, Welfare, Income, Wealth, Religion, and Philanthropy
  • N31 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N32 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • Browse content in N4 - Government, War, Law, International Relations, and Regulation
  • N42 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • N43 - Europe: Pre-1913
  • Browse content in N5 - Agriculture, Natural Resources, Environment, and Extractive Industries
  • N50 - General, International, or Comparative
  • Browse content in N7 - Transport, Trade, Energy, Technology, and Other Services
  • N70 - General, International, or Comparative
  • Browse content in N9 - Regional and Urban History
  • N91 - U.S.; Canada: Pre-1913
  • N92 - U.S.; Canada: 1913-
  • Browse content in O - Economic Development, Innovation, Technological Change, and Growth
  • Browse content in O1 - Economic Development
  • O12 - Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development
  • O16 - Financial Markets; Saving and Capital Investment; Corporate Finance and Governance
  • O17 - Formal and Informal Sectors; Shadow Economy; Institutional Arrangements
  • Browse content in O3 - Innovation; Research and Development; Technological Change; Intellectual Property Rights
  • O31 - Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives
  • O32 - Management of Technological Innovation and R&D
  • O33 - Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes
  • O35 - Social Innovation
  • Browse content in O5 - Economywide Country Studies
  • O57 - Comparative Studies of Countries
  • Browse content in P - Economic Systems
  • Browse content in P1 - Capitalist Systems
  • P16 - Political Economy
  • Browse content in P2 - Socialist Systems and Transitional Economies
  • P26 - Political Economy; Property Rights
  • Browse content in P3 - Socialist Institutions and Their Transitions
  • P37 - Legal Institutions; Illegal Behavior
  • Browse content in P4 - Other Economic Systems
  • P45 - International Trade, Finance, Investment, and Aid
  • P48 - Political Economy; Legal Institutions; Property Rights; Natural Resources; Energy; Environment; Regional Studies
  • Browse content in Q - Agricultural and Natural Resource Economics; Environmental and Ecological Economics
  • Browse content in Q3 - Nonrenewable Resources and Conservation
  • Q34 - Natural Resources and Domestic and International Conflicts
  • Browse content in R - Urban, Rural, Regional, Real Estate, and Transportation Economics
  • Browse content in R1 - General Regional Economics
  • R12 - Size and Spatial Distributions of Regional Economic Activity
  • Browse content in R3 - Real Estate Markets, Spatial Production Analysis, and Firm Location
  • R30 - General
  • Browse content in Z - Other Special Topics
  • Browse content in Z1 - Cultural Economics; Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology
  • Z11 - Economics of the Arts and Literature
  • Z13 - Economic Sociology; Economic Anthropology; Social and Economic Stratification
  • Z18 - Public Policy
  • Browse content in Z2 - Sports Economics
  • Z20 - General
  • Advance articles
  • Editor's Choice
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • About The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising and Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Dispatch Dates
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Issue Cover

Article Contents

1. introduction, 2. related research, 3. baseline framework, 4. baseline results, 5. extensions, 6. insights, 7. final remarks, supplementary material, acknowledgments, data availability.

  • < Previous

Organizational dynamics: culture, design, and performance

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

Timothy Besley, Torsten Persson, Organizational dynamics: culture, design, and performance, The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization , Volume 40, Issue 2, July 2024, Pages 394–415, https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewac020

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

We examine the two-way interplay between organizational cultures and organizational design, where culture is modeled as the prevailing social identities among workplace groups that can affect project choices. In a setting where cultural dynamics depend on the expected relative payoffs of holding different identities, we investigate how tribalism and charismatic leadership shape organizational dynamics and steady-state cultures. We show how a strong culture can be a virtue when it permits greater delegated authority, but a vice when the culture is poorly aligned with organizational objectives. We apply our analysis to concrete debates about the interaction of design, performance, and culture ( JEL L23, M14).

A key question in economics—and the social sciences more broadly—is why private or public organizations in similar environments perform so differently. Economists have looked for answers primarily in terms of institution design, such as organization boundaries or authority structures. Other social scientists have looked for answers in terms of less tangible elements, such as organizational cultures or work-force motivations. This article synthesizes these approaches by putting forward a tractable dynamic model of organizational culture, design, and performance.

The key design choice in our model is how much power to decentralize in the organization. As in Aghion and Tirole (1997) , this involves trading off the benefits from higher productivity against the costs from conflicting interests between leaders and managers. Following Akerlof and Kranton (2000) , the organization’s managers have identities that are associated with particular values and thus shape conflicting interests between leaders and managers. It is precisely this composition of group identities that we refer to as the organization’s culture at a given point in time. Culture evolves over time and we explore the drivers of these dynamics along with the two-way interactions between culture and organization design.

A key distinction in the model is between what we call individual and tribal identities. The former identities only affect perceived conflicts of interest at the level of individuals, while the latter allow for in-group altruism and hence for conflicts at the level of groups. Group-based identities do not just affect the strength of identity-based preferences; if in-group motives are powerful enough, they can reshape the nature of the organization’s cultural dynamics.

With individual identities, the organization converges to a unique interior steady-state culture, which does not maximize the organization’s long-run performance. This result can be attributed to lack of commitment. Adding the possibility of charismatic leaders—who are able to persuade managers to follow organizational goals—a long-run culture may permit a greater use of performance-enhancing decentralization.

With sufficiently powerful tribal identities, a complementarity emerges between the share of agents that conform to a certain identity and the attractiveness of holding that identity. This results in divergent dynamics where an organization may converge to a suboptimal monoculture. Moreover, culture, design, and performance can become path-dependent. Such path dependence results in organizational inertia that may prevent adaptability.

Methodologically speaking, our analysis pinpoints a source of inefficiency, which is conceptually distinct from the informational problems underlying most previous work in economics on organizational performance. In particular, the model conveys four new substantive insights. First, the organization’s culture may drive both its design and performance, producing a “spurious correlation” between decentralization (centralization) and good (bad) performance. Second, a strong organizational culture can be both a virtue and a vice: it allows the organization to exploit the performance gains from decentralization in a stable environment, but it can prevent or slow down adjustments when the environment changes. Third, cultural path dependence may explain the common observation that organizations can develop different authority structures and performance levels in the same environment. Fourth, leadership traits are important for long-run cultures and performance: a charismatic leader who influences management can circumvent the downside of entrenched cultures, but this is more difficult with dysfunctional tribal cultures.

The article is organized as follows. Section 2 offers a brief discussion of related research. In Section 3, we formulate our baseline model. Section 4 spells out its main results. In Section 5, we extend the baseline model to allow for tribal cultures and charismatic leaders. Section 6 illustrates our substantive and methodological insights with examples from the real world as well as the existing literature. We conclude in Section 7. Some details and background materials are relegated to an Online Appendix .

The article is related to the economics literature on how strategic design of organizational boundaries and authority structures may shape performance, following classic contributions by Coase (1937) , Williamson (1979) , and Grossman and Hart (1986) . We build on a branch of this research where conflicting interests influence the organization’s delegation of decision-making, with key theoretical contributions by Aghion and Tirole (1997) , Alonso et al. (2008) , Bolton and Farrell (1990) , Hart and Holmström (2010) , and Rantakari (2012) . As in that literature, our model’s designer trades off costs of decentralizing power, due to conflicting interests and coordination, against benefits, due to higher productivity. But the extent of delegation evolves endogenously across time and shifts across states of the world, as the organization’s external environment and its internal culture interact.

Outside economics, performance differences are frequently attributed to heterogeneous organizational cultures ( Whyte 1956 ; Hofstede 1984 ; Wilson 1989 ; Schein 1990 ). Some economists sympathize with this notion, but have not reached a consensus on how to formally represent such cultures. Influential papers have focused on beliefs, often in overlapping-generations models. Kreps (1990) models corporate cultures as belief-based norms in games with overlapping generations of agents, where cooperation is sustained by threats of poor future performance. Tirole (1996) studies belief-based individual and collective reputations, which can produce persistently different organizational performance indicators such as corruption levels. Dessi (2008) shows how information transmission across generations may create distinct cultures through collective memory, while Benabou (2013) shows how organizations may develop common beliefs that induce groupthink. Greif (1994) sees belief-based cultural differences as solutions to (different) commitment problems, and collectivist cultures as more supportive of cooperation.

Unlike much of the economics literature, our approach to organizational culture is not belief-based. Instead, it relates to four main ideas in existing strands of research, inside and outside of economics.

First, we model culture as the distribution of types in an organization, as in Lazear (1995) . This conforms to the voluminous literature on organizational cultures (see e.g., Schein 1990 ), influenced by sociology, psychology, and anthropology. In broad terms, our approach follows Tajfel (1974) , who argues that social identities create within-group loyalty and out-group hostility. This idea has been picked up in studies of organizations by sociologists (e.g., Ashforth and Mael 1989 ) and economists (e.g., Akerlof and Kranton 2000 ; Besley and Ghatak 2005 ). The approach parallels a large literature in business economics and organization theory on conflicts of interest inside firms, which goes all the way back to Cyert and March (1963) .

Second, we suppose that organizational culture is transmitted across generations of employees via socialization where successful types replicate faster. This relates to economic studies of socialization and culture, as surveyed by Bisin and Verdier (2011) . Our specific model focuses on changes in values—rather than in behavior or beliefs—following the lead of Güth and Yaari (1992) , Güth (1995) , and Alger and Weibull (2013) . More generally, these dynamics relate to research on cultural evolution [e.g., the seminal work of Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman (1981) and Boyd and Richerson (1985) ], as well as on evolutionary dynamics in population games (reviewed in Sandholm 2010 ).

Third, we study an organization’s adaptability as its capacity for cultural flexibility. This idea is related to Teece et al. (1997) , who argue that adaptability is a core capability of the firm, and to Rantakari (2008) , who considers the relationship between adaptability and the delegation of authority. The interplay between delegation and organizational culture, and between organizational culture and inertia, is also discussed in Van den Steen (2010a ). Dessein (2002) formalizes the idea that a key efficiency loss of delegation is a failure to exploit local information.

Dessein and Prat (2017) study organizational capital which they define as an intangible, slow-moving, productive asset. This notion has much in common with a slow-moving culture. However, in our core model, culture reproduces through the interaction of employees without input from leaders while, in their core model, the leadership can influence organizational capital. That is similar to the extension of our model with charismatic leadership. Van den Steen (2010b) discusses how a manager’s beliefs influence corporate culture and how culture originates through screening, self-sorting, and manager-directed joint learning. Gibbons and Henderson (2012) survey the emerging literature on how management shapes firm-level productivity.

Fourth, our model sheds additional light on an economics literature about management that links decentralization—or other aspects of structure—to firm performance. For example, Bloom et al. (2012) study empirically decentralization of firms, and find productivity gains from decentralization associated with greater levels of trust. In our analysis, decentralization and performance are both endogenous and (partly) depend on organizational culture. Thus, a correlation between performance and decentralization might be driven by culture (as an omitted variable).

Measurements of cultural differences across time and place were largely developed outside of economics. For example, Hofstede (1984) began a body of research that compares organizational cultures across countries, assuming that cross-country cultural differences rub off on organizations active in those countries. Hofstede et al. (2010) offer a survey of the extensive evidence that has been collected. The well-known World Values Survey was partly structured so as to examine international differences in values (see Inglehart et al. 2004 ). Over time, empirical studies of culture have also spread to economics [see Alesina and Giuliano (2015) and Guiso et al. (2006) for overviews]. While most of these studies concern individuals, Guiso et al. (2013) show how cultures that foster integrity tend to improve corporate performance.

In this section, we describe our core model of organizational design and culture, beginning with a static framework where identities are fixed. We then allow identities to evolve over time.

3.1 Organizational structure and hierarchy

An organization has a continuum of divisions, indexed by ω ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] , each of which must work on a project in every time period, indexed by t . (The time horizon is infinite.) There is a three-tier hierarchy: a leader of the whole organization, a senior manager in each division, and a junior manager working for each senior manager.

The leader faithfully serves the interests of the principal(s), such as the owners of a firm, a government ministry, or members of a political party. A senior manager of division ω can be one of two identity types, τ ( ω ) ∈ { 0 , 1 } . We denote by μ t the share of identity-0 senior managers in the whole organization at t . Junior managers become senior managers in period t  +   1 and are socialized by interacting with the period- t senior managers. 1

3.2 States, projects, and decentralization

Payoffs depend on an aggregate state θ ∈ { 0 , 1 } which favors one kind of project choice and captures the current climate in which the organization operates. It is drawn afresh each period with iid draws over time with the probability of outcome θ  = 0 being β . The environment is more predictable when β is close to zero or one.

A project choice ρ ( ω , θ ) ∈ { 0 , 1 } is made at the division level and can hence vary with ω . The leader can take over that choice in some divisions, which we refer to as centralization . Moreover, she determines the extent of decentralization— that is, the share of divisions d ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] where the senior manager is permitted to choose ρ ( ω , θ ) ⁠ .

3.3 Leaders

The leader observes θ and knows the identity composition of senior managers, captured by μ , but cannot observe (or verify) individual managers’ types. Neither can the leader verify the projects ρ ( ω , θ ) chosen in decentralized divisions. We thus follow Aghion and Tirole (1997) in abstracting from allowing contracts—state-contingent or not—to shape decentralized project choices.

The leader’s (and organization’s) payoff in each division depends on the state, θ , and the project choice ρ ( ω , θ ) ⁠ . If these do not match, ρ ( ω , θ ) ≠ θ ⁠ , the payoff is 0. If they do match and the divisional choice is decentralized, the payoff is 1. However, centralization leads to an efficiency loss, at the division level. Even if ρ ( ω , θ ) = θ ⁠ , the payoff is π with 0 < π < 1. We think about this cost as primarily reflecting an (unmodeled) failure to exploit local information. For example, Bolton and Farrell (1990) model the informational losses as centralized decision making it harder for organizations to find least cost solutions. They argue that trial and error at the local level might help discover new ways of completing a task.

By centralizing the choice in a division, the leader can guarantee that ρ ( ω , θ ) = θ ⁠ . Even though decentralization has a divisional benefit, 1 − π ⁠ , we assume that it has a cost at the organization level. For any share of decentralized divisions d , this cost is given by an increasing convex function ϕ ( d ) with 1 − π > ϕ d ( 0 ) ⁠ . We think about this cost as primarily reflecting the (organization-wide) lack of coordination associated with decentralization. The convexity assumption turns the leader’s decentralization decision into a concave problem.

3.4 Managers

The variable Q ( θ , τ ) denotes the share of all managers of the same type τ for whom ρ ( ω , θ ) = τ ( ω ) ⁠ . This share of project-matched type- τ managers has a positive payoff, of u , while the complementary share 1 − Q ( θ , τ ) has a payoff of zero. It follows that u μ Q ( θ , τ ) is the total payoff in state θ to a type- τ senior manager’s own identity group. Setting ξ > 0 is then a simple way of capturing the idea of tribal cultures, as discussed in the organizational psychology literature (see e.g., Kovach 2017 ). In our model, organizational tribalism thus takes the form of within-group loyalty, or altruism.

In the following, we consider two cases. The first is individual identities with ξ = 0. The second is tribal identities with ξ > 0 and the strength of tribalism captured by the level of ξ . As we shall see, individual and tribal identities can imply very different organizational dynamics.

3.5 Organizational culture

We refer to μ t —the share of identity-0 managers at t— as the organization’s culture. In state θ = 0 , the leader’s preferences align with those of type τ  = 0 managers, but clash with preferences of type τ  = 1 managers, and vice versa in state θ  = 1. The latent leader–manager conflict of interest thus varies both across states, with θ , and across time, with μ t . This conflict crucially influences the leader’s willingness to decentralize projects so as to take advantage of higher efficiency.

3.6 Cultural transmission

In equation (3) , Δ t + 1 is a measure of the expected “cultural-fitness advantage” of identity-0 relative to identity-1 at t + 1 , the value of which we derive below. Formally, Δ t + 1 equals the expected period- t  +   1 payoff of a manager with type τ  = 0 minus the expected period- t  +   1 payoff of a manager with type τ  = 1. We can write this expression in terms of the leader’s optimal decentralization decisions, which we do in equation (5) . The function   G ( · ) is a c.d.f. representing the distribution of (idiosyncratic) socialization costs/benefits, which we assume is symmetric around 0—that is, G ( 0 ) = 1 2 .

Equation (3) shows that Δ t + 1 plays a key role in the analysis and reflects whether one type is expected to thrive more in future in an organization. If it does, then there will be more successful socialization toward the thriving type. The Online Appendix shows how equation (3) can be grounded in a specific micro-founded model of oblique organizational socialization, which mirrors the approach in the evolutionary anthropology literature mentioned in Section 2. Specifically, we base our socialization model on Bidner and Francois (2011) , by assuming that each junior manager is randomly matched for mentoring purposes with a specific senior manager. He will encounter a type-0 manager with probability μ t and will himself become type-0 with probability G ( Δ t + 1 ) ⁠ . Even if such direct socialization fails, we allow for indirect socialization with the probability of becoming a type-0 depending on the average fraction of such types in the organization.

The important general idea embodied in equation (3) is a “Darwinian” transmission process, where the share of a certain identity group is growing whenever that group is expected to do better. This forward-looking formulation, based on expected utility, is different from evolutionary models, where a new generation is just trying to copy some existing types. It also differs from strategic economic models, such as the one in Bisin and Verdier (2001) , where members of an earlier generation try to inculcate their own type on members of a later generation.

The organization evolves over time, with all relevant variables indexed by t ⁠ . The full timing of the model within each period t is as follows:

There is an initial share μ t of senior managers with identity τ = 0   ⁠ .

Nature determines θ t ∈ { 0 , 1 } ⁠ .

New junior managers enter and are randomly assigned to divisions.

The organization’s leader chooses the fraction of decentralized divisions d t ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] ⁠ .

Junior managers are socialized, which determines μ t + 1 ⁠ .

The leader chooses projects   ρ ( ω , θ t ) in each centralized division, while the senior manager chooses the project in each decentralized division.

Payoffs are realized.

Senior managers retire and are replaced by the existing junior managers who are randomly assigned to divisions.

This section derives and discusses our main results, which are recorded in three propositions.

4.1 Organization design

A corner solution, δ ( μ ) = 1 for μ < 1 , arises if 1 − π > ϕ d ( 1 ) ⁠ . □

To understand the proposition, suppose that θ = 0 ⁠ , then there are two possibilities. If μ ≤ π ⁠ , d  =   0, and the organization is fully centralized—the lack of alignment between state 0 and the fraction of managers who prefer ρ ( ω , θ ) = θ = 0 ⁠ , as well as the coordination cost ϕ ( d ) ⁠ , push against decentralization. However, if μ > π ⁠ , it can become beneficial to decentralize the choice of ρ ( ω , θ )   in some divisions, as these divisions will produce an additional payoff of 1 − π ⁠ . But this gain must be weighed against the marginal coordination cost ϕ d associated with decentralization. Maximal decentralization, δ ( 1 ) ⁠ , occurs when μ  = 1. An analogous argument applies when the state θ = 1.

Proposition 1 shows that culture, as measured by μ , shapes organizational decision-making by affecting the conflict of interest between the leader and senior management. Greater alignment fosters decentralization. However, since the leader’s optimal decisions are state-dependent, she may occasionally “take back control” of previously decentralized decisions, depending on the realization of θ . How often this happens depends on β and μ . For example, if β is high decisions are more likely decentralized when μ is high compared with when μ is low. 2

The model predicts that we should observe higher performance in more decentralized organizations. But this is merely a correlation, rather than a causal effect of decentralization, since the decision to decentralize is endogenous and depends on θ and μ .

4.2 Equilibrium Cultural Fitness

This can be used to explore how cultural fitness depends on μ and ξ which will be key to the cultural/identity dynamics.

The condition implies that the root of the difference equation (3) is always positive, but below (above) unity when Δ μ has a negative (positive) sign. (The Online Appendix offers a further discussion, which also ties in with the analysis in Sections 4.2 and 5.1.)

4.3 Steady-state cultures

This assumption will always hold when δ ( 1 ) → 1 or β is close enough to 1 2 ⁠ .

If equation (7) holds and identities are individually held, there is a unique stable interior steady-state μ ^ , defined by Δ ( μ ^ , 0 ) = 0.

Since equation (6) holds, it follows from equation (3) that μ t = μ t + 1 if and only if G ( Δ ( μ ^ , 0 ) ) = 1 / 2 which holds only if Δ ( μ ^ , 0 ) = 0 ⁠ . Moreover, this interior steady state is stable since μ t + 1 > μ t for all Δ t + 1 > 0 and μ t + 1 < μ t for all Δ t + 1 < 0 ⁠ . □

The equilibrium dynamics associated with Proposition 2 are illustrated in the top panel of Figure 1 . The growth of μ —which is determined by 2 μ ( 1 − μ ) G ( Δ ( μ , ξ ) ) —is plotted on the y -axis. It is positive (negative) when μ —plotted on the x -axis—is below (above) μ ^ . The chevrons in the diagram indicate that culture converges to an interior steady state μ ^ from any starting point.

Alternative cultural dynamics.

Alternative cultural dynamics.

Intuitively, the result arises because managers who are of minority identity are more likely to be delegated authority when it really matters to them—that is, when their preferences conflict with those of the leader. On the contrary, managers with a majority identity are more likely to be delegated authority when their preferences align with those of the leader. This pattern of leader decisions favors minority identities and prevents a monoculture from arising.

4.4 Comparative statics

If β = 1 / 2 ⁠ , then μ ^ = 1 / 2 ⁠ . Moreover, if equation (7) holds, then μ ^ is increasing in β .

Because δ ( μ ) is an increasing function (by Proposition 1), ∂ μ ^ / ∂ β is positive, whenever there are interior solutions for δ ( · ) ⁠ . □

The steady-state equilibrium culture has exactly half the managers of each type when the state is maximally uncertain, at β = 1 / 2 ⁠ . However, as β moves away from 1/2, steady-state culture adapts and settles at an interior point where a larger fraction of managers are better suited to most likely aggregate state of the world θ . Decentralization at the steady-state culture depends on the alignment of this culture with θ . The organization will look “conflictual” some of the time, when the leadership centralizes control to improve performance in the wake of shifts in θ . The comparative statics with respect to π , the cost of decentralization is ambiguous as a shift in π reduces the amount of decentralization in all states of the world. 3

4.5 Optimality?

Is the steady-state culture pinned down by Proposition 2 optimal from the organization’s (and the leader’s) perspective? To explore this question, we need to choose a benchmark. In an unconstrained world, the organization would like to choose a culture each period depending on the realization of θ ⁠ . An optimally chosen state-dependent culture would always be a monoculture, which can take maximum advantage of decentralization. 4 But an agile and instantly adaptable process like this is not compatible with viewing culture in terms of manager organization-specific identities as a source of inertia where governance structure responds to θ .

The long-run payoff of the organization is maximized by a monoculture with either μ = 1 (only identity-0 managers) or μ = 0 (only identity-1 managers), with μ = 1 ( μ = 0) being preferred when β > 1 / 2 ( ⁠ β < 1 / 2 ⁠ ).

since δ ( 0 ) = 0 ⁠ . This expression is positive iff β > 1 / 2 , since 1 − π > ϕ d ( 0 ) ⁠ . □

If equation (7) holds and identities are individual, the equilibrium steady-state culture is suboptimal for the organization.

Our baseline model thus predicts that, in any long-run equilibrium, the organization is multicultural. This leads to worse performance for the organization than with a long-run optimal culture. The other side of this coin is that some conflict of interest between the leader and managers remains whichever the realized state.

4.6 Lack of commitment

In our framework, the leader cannot choose μ directly, although the path of μ still reflects expected organizational-design decisions. However, the reason for the long-run suboptimality is not that leaders have a short-run (one-period) horizon, but rather their lack of commitment. Even if a leader cares about long-run payoffs, she is unable to commit herself to future levels of d in order to influence the path of μ . As we now argue, any attempt to promise a sequence of such choices would therefore run into a generic credibility (time-consistency) problem.

To see the nature of the problem, note that to influence long-run payoffs, the leader at t would like to promise d t + 1 = 0 ⁠ , which would yield Δ ( μ , 0 ) = u ( 2 β − 1 ) . This, in turn, would push the organization’s culture toward μ  = 1 ( ⁠ μ = 0 ) whenever β > 1 / 2 ( ⁠ β < 1 / 2 ⁠ )—that is, in the right direction as per Proposition 3. But promising d t + 1 = 0 is not credible, as the short-run optimum generally has d ( θ ) > 0 —that is, once θ t + 1 is revealed it may be valuable to decentralize decisions to maximize current payoffs, as per Proposition 1. With commitment, an optimal path for decentralization would find the right trade-off between short-run and long-run payoffs (we sketch out this argument more fully in the Online Appendix ).

This observation about the downside of being unable to commit is reminiscent of discussions around the failure of the Coase theorem ( Coase 1960 ) in dynamic settings without commitment. In particular, it parallels the argument in Acemoglu (2003) , who shows how a lack of commitment by current decision-makers may be a key impediment to efficiency in dynamic political models.

A possible substitute for commitment in our setting would be for the principals to strategically delegate control of the organization to a leader who favors one particular culture over another, even though this culture is suboptimal in the short-run. This would be particularly relevant if the (otherwise unachievable) commitment path would prescribe either d t = 1 or d t = 0 for all time. 5 However, we show below that the long-run optimum may also be achievable without commitment if the leader is charismatic in a specific sense.

This section develops a richer analysis, by extending the baseline model in two ways, each of which is summarized in a new proposition. These new results come in handy when we develop insights from the model in the next section.

5.1 Tribal identities

Now suppose that ξ > 0 , corresponding to the case of tribal identities discussed in the organizational psychology literature. Tribalism does not affect the decentralization decisions in Proposition 1. However, it sows the seed of a dynamic complementarity between the size of a group and this group’s cultural-fitness advantage. As we shall see, this may alter Proposition 2.

5.1.1 Divergent dynamics

In particular, for strong enough tribalism—meaning large enough ξ —we can have Δ ( μ , ξ )   increasing in μ . In words, the expectation that more future managers will have a particular identity makes it more attractive to select that identity during socialization. This complementarity will result in divergent dynamics with alternative steady states and initial conditions shaping the long-run equilibrium.

Suppose that equation (8) holds and identities are tribal. Then, for β close enough to 1/2, δ ( 1 ) < 1 , and ξ high enough, there exists μ ˜ ( β ) ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] such that if μ 0 > μ ˜ ( β ) , an identity-0 monoculture emerges in the long run ( lim t → ∞ μ t = 1 ) . But if μ 0 < μ ˜ ( β ) , an identity-1 monoculture emerges in the long run ( lim t → ∞ μ t = 0 ) ⁠ .

The possibility of two steady states is illustrated graphically in the bottom panel of Figure 1 . It shows how the growth of μ —determined by

2 μ ( 1 − μ ) G ( Δ ( μ , ξ ) ) —is now negative (positive) as μ is below (above) the point μ ˜ ( β ) , implying divergent dynamics toward μ  = 0 ( μ  = 1).

Proposition 4 vividly illustrates how having a tribal culture can be a virtue. With ξ  = 0, we found that the organization never fully converges to the leader’s optimal long-run culture. But such a monoculture is now possible with strong enough tribalism. However, strong tribal cultures may also have a downside, as we discuss next.

5.1.2 The wrong culture?

Proposition 4 says that, if tribal identities are strong enough, we have path dependence and convergence to alternative steady states depending on the initial value of μ . This result strengthens the argument that equilibrium culture may not be optimal from a leader’s perspective. For example, if μ 0 is small enough and ξ is large enough, then the organization converges to an identity-1 monoculture with μ = 0 , even though the organization would be better off with μ = 1. Thus, tribalism may drive the organization’s culture in the “wrong” direction.

5.1.3 Inertia

Proposition 4 also reveals the possibility of organizational inertia in the tribal-culture model. In the baseline model without tribalism, long-run equilibrium culture, μ ^ ⁠ , responds to changes in the model’s parameters. With tribalism, however, organizational culture can be unresponsive to exogenous shocks over some parameter range. This inertia rhymes with frequent (informal) claims that a tribal culture may limit organizational adaptability.

To illustrate this point, suppose that β increases from β ′ < 1 2 to β ″ > 1 2 . By Proposition 3, this shifts the long-run optimal culture from μ  = 0 to μ = 1. Assume further that the shift in β occurs when μ has converged far enough toward μ  = 0 that μ < μ ˜ ( β ″ ) . Then, convergence toward a—now dysfunctional—type-1 monoculture will continue, despite the shift in β .

The organization only adapts when a certain shock—like a shift in β —is large enough. But even if culture starts moving in the right long-run direction, the organization will suffer a productivity decline along the adjustment path due to more centralization of project choices as long as culture is maladapted. We believe that this observation is relevant in concrete applications of our ideas, such as to the history of IBM (discussed in Section 6).

5.1.4 A Broader interpretation of tribalism?

Our model associates tribal identification with altruism. But the actual role of tribal identification may be considerably broader and include other characteristics that raise the probability that the next generation of managers inherits the most common type from the previous generation. Altruism is one factor in this decision, but other factors might include choices by the organization, such as how it trains or mentors new managers, the types of “team-building” exercises that it encourages, and the extent to which a new manager interacts with a broad cross-section of older managers. It would be interesting to extend our formal analysis with further microfoundations that incorporate some of these features.

5.2 Charismatic leaders

So far, a leader’s influence has been limited to deciding in how many divisions to decentralize project choices and how to choose projects in the remaining, centralized divisions. But as emphasized in the management literature, some leaders may have enough “charisma” that they can influence the intrinsic motivation of managers, and persuade those with identity τ ≠ θ to act in line with the organization’s objectives. 7

5.2.1 Leader persuasiveness

To make the main points as simply as possible, we introduce an almost trivial model of charismatic leaders, which still captures the essence in Weber (1922) . The extended model serves to show how culture and leadership influence can interact, including the limits in guiding an organization toward an optimal culture.

Let κ be the additional utility boost managers obtain if they follow a certain leader’s plea for setting ρ ( ω , θ ) = θ . Managers with τ = θ already have aligned motives, so this boost just increases their payoff from following their identity. But for non-aligned managers with τ ≠ θ , the payoff from following their identity becomes weaker. Finally, assume that leaders vary in their persuasiveness, and that some leaders are charismatic with κ > u ⁠ . Such leaders will lead non-aligned managers to change their decisions just to please the leader. 8

(a) Charismatic leaders always choose d ( 0 ) = d ( 1 ) = δ ( 1 ) . (b) If the organization has a charismatic leader and identity is individually held, ξ = 0, it converges to its optimal long-run culture. (c) If the leader is charismatic and identity is tribal, with ξ positive and large enough, there exists μ ˜ ( β ) ∈ [ 0 , 1 ] such that if μ 0 > μ ˜ ( β )   ( ⁠ μ 0 < μ ˜ ( β ) ⁠ ) an identity-0 (identity-1) monoculture emerges in the long run.

Result (a) follows because all managers set ρ ( ω , θ ) = θ , whenever κ > u . A charismatic leader can thus choose maximal decentralization (given coordination costs), whichever the state.

In other words, μ converges toward μ  = 1 when β > 1 / 2 and μ = 0 when β < 1 / 2 ⁠ .

Clearly, Δ μ ( μ , ξ ) > 0 in this case. The rest of the argument follows the same lines as in Proposition 4, with μ ˜ ( β ) defined by Δ ( μ ˜ ( β ) , ξ ) ) = 0 , which is interior when ξ is large enough or β is not too far from 1 / 2. For example, when β = 1 / 2 ⁠ , the critical value is given by μ ˜ ( β ) = 1 / 2. □

With individual identities, a charismatic leader can afford to decentralize more and this yields higher payoffs. By shaping expected payoffs, such a leader also guarantees convergence to the optimal long-run monoculture. But for this path to materialize in the long run, a charismatic leader must remain in place. If not, the organization reverts toward the interior solution in Proposition 2.

Proposition 5(c) shows the limitations to charismatic leadership. We have already seen in Proposition 4 that cultures based on tribal identities can lead to a complementarity between payoffs and the share of each type in the organization. So even if a charismatic leader is able to decentralize more, expected payoffs also depend on the initial value of μ . Indeed, the organization may now again have more than one steady state. This means that a charismatic leader—even if she were guaranteed to stay in place—no longer ensures convergence to the organization’s optimal culture. The organization does converge to a monoculture, but this need not be the one that maximizes its long-run payoff.

In this section, we illustrate some insights that emanate from the model.

6.1 Strong cultures can be a virtue and a vice: IBM

The organizational culture in IBM has been the subject of extensive discussion. Indeed, some of the most influential work on corporate cultures has focused on IBM, including the classic work of Hofstede (1984) . Leading textbooks on the origins of corporate success, such as Peters and Waterman (1982) , also feature the company as a prominent example. As a case study, IBM illustrates two key insights from our model.

The alignment between IBM’s inside culture and outside demands has been given pride of place in explaining the ebb and flow of the company’s fortunes [ Cortada (2018) surveys this research]. The company thrived on developing a strong culture focused on producing mainframes. Indeed, IBM was the undisputed leader in the mainframe market 50 years ago, with a share of the overall computer market of 60% in 1970. By 1980, it still had a 62% share of the mainframe-computer market, but its share of the overall market had declined to 32%. This largely reflected IBM’s under-performance in the fast-growing mini-computer market. In 1979, this led Business Week to label IBM as a “stodgy, mature company,” a view corroborated by a 20% decline in the price of IBM stock.

To espouse the new personal-computer industry, the firm began developing the now-famed IBM PC, which prompted the quip that “IBM bringing out a personal computer would be like teaching an elephant to tap dance.” In line with our model, Mills (1996) emphasizes how an ingrained culture was a central reason for the slow response to a changing environment.

But why did IBM have such a strong culture in the first place? This and subsequent developments can be seen through the lens of our model. For the 15 years from 1956 to 1971, Thomas Watson Jr. held the CEO position, which he had taken over from his own father. Watson Jr. is universally described as a charismatic leader ( ⁠ κ > u in the model), who spearheaded the company’s switch from punch-card to mainframe technology. Upon taking over the CEO position, he reorganized the company into a divisional structure and decentralized many decisions (increased d ). Watson continued to build a strong mainframe-oriented culture (managers adopted identity τ = 0 , associated with mainframe projects in a mainframe world ρ = θ = 0 , by Proposition 5). His reign was in the heyday of IBM’s success and market dominance in what our model would portray as a predictable environment favoring mainframes ( β close to 1). At such a time, IBM would benefit from a strong mainframe-oriented culture, well aligned with market trends, that permitted the company to reap the productivity gains from extensive decentralization (a high value of d ( 0 ) , by Proposition 1).

But the CEOs who succeeded Watson Jr. after his resignation—Vincent Learson and Frank Cary—did not have the same charisma in leading senior management ( ⁠ κ < u ⁠ ). We believe that this is also a key part of IBM’s story. As the market turned away from mainframes (a fall in β ), our model would indeed predict a sustained fall in performance because the strong mainframe culture led to inertial adjustment (by Proposition 4). The performance fall would result from less decentralization as the market turned toward PCs, as the latter was not well aligned with IBM’s prevailing mainframe culture (the leader setting d (1) low when θ  = 1 and μ is high, by Proposition 1). Even though the company eventually found its way back to profitability, the slow adjustment could be explained by slow cultural dynamics.

To us, a model where culture built on identity is a state variable appears better suited to explaining these dynamics than a model of organizational culture built on beliefs. The analytic narrative of IBM’s history we have developed clearly brings out how a strong organizational culture can be both a virtue and a vice. It is a virtue when it supports extensive decentralization in a stable environment, but a vice when it sustains inertia in a changing environment.

6.2 Coexisting culture and design differences: public bureaucracies

Another key feature of our model is that—with tribalism—different organizations in the same environment can end up with different cultures and designs. We believe that this applies to many public bureaucracies, which seem to operate and perform very differently, in spite of similar levels of funding and other conditions. For that reason, they also seem extremely difficult to reform.

How much local control to offer in the delivery of public services has been discussed in research on education and health-care provision [see e.g., Wilson (1989) and Ahmad et al. (2005) ]. Decentralization is frequently claimed to work best in taking advantage of local conditions, when the objectives of the center and delivery units are aligned.

Honig (2018) stresses a similar point in a different context, namely that of international-aid organizations. He contrasts the relatively decentralized practices of the United Kingdom’s Department for International Development (DFID) with the penchant for centralized management in the US Agency for International Development (USAID). How can we understand this difference through the lens of our model?

We first note that DFID operations are very much oriented toward collaboration with host governments. Decentralized provision of aid can indeed be thought of as giving power to NGOs to make key project choices, rather than trying to impose these from above. Our model would interpret this as a situation where the prevailing culture among country managers and the objectives of DFID leaders are well aligned.

However, USAID operations are much more oriented toward supporting host-country, private-sector projects. Our model suggests that the more centralized design of USAID can be interpreted in two different ways, which both reflect lacking alignment between leadership and country managers. In one interpretation, the objectives of DFID and USAID leaders are similar, but the culture of USAID officers has developed in a different direction. In the other, USAID country officers espouse the same culture as DFID officers, but the leadership has different objectives. It would be interesting to conduct a case study along these lines.

6.3 Performance and decentralization: causation or correlation?

Our model gives insights into the management literature which links decentralization—or other forms of design—and firm performance. For instance, Bloom et al. (2012) study empirically the decentralization of firms, and find productivity gains from decentralization associated with greater levels of trust. Bandiera et al. (2016) examine how CEOs use their scarce time, especially when it comes to their involvement in production versus coordination.

In our setting, decisions to decentralize are endogenous and partly reflect how well the culture is matched to the state of the world. Therefore, we would indeed expect a correlation between performance and decentralization. However, culture could be an important omitted variable in mediating this relationship.

Bloom et al. (2015) do find differences in public-bureaucracy management styles to be correlated with performance indicators. However, management practices and performance are likely to be co-determined with factors that help shape organizational cultures. Indeed, our model suggests that management practices should be a key manifestation of organizational culture. How far these cultures, or their drivers, have changed over time does not appear to have been systematically studied.

We have shown how identities held by sequential generations of managers may give rise to organizational-culture dynamics that interact with organizational-design choices. In our model, culture moves slower than design choices and is the only state variable. This model generates a range of substantive and methodological insights into the two-way dynamics between organizational culture and design, with implications for performance. By modeling culture as a state variable based on identity formation, we can see why generating cultural change amounts to more than shifting beliefs: design choices that maximize short-run payoffs shape the long-run evolution of organizational culture. These insights complement the insights from studies based on informational frictions.

Though our framework is very simple, it offers insights into debates about organizational culture. It suggests that a strong culture can be both a virtue and a vice, and it helps us understand when charismatic leaders can bring about more cultural homogeneity. But our framework also shows how cultures and leaders may interact with the stability of the organization’s environment. Applying these insights, we get a fresh perspective on the extensive literatures in business history and organizational behavior on the ups and downs of IBM.

Our model also helps to understand how organizations, which operate in the same environment, may develop different authority structures and performance levels. Recognizing that agency problems exist, however, may not fully account for these performance differences. To explain them further, it would be natural to extend the analysis with endogenous effort. This would rely on the natural assumption that intrinsically motivated managers are prepared to exert more effort. That kind of extension would enrich the analysis of tribal cultures (the Online Appendix sketches such an extension).

One could also extend our analysis in other directions. Perhaps most importantly, if conflicting interests due to culture is indeed a source of inefficiency, then we would expect organizations to try and circumvent that problem. We have assumed that limited verifiability makes it impossible to “contract around it.” But in passing we have already mentioned how our analysis suggests motives for strategic recruitment or strategic delegation. In a richer setting, the cultural issues we have stressed may thus help us understand organizational-design features, which are different from those identified by the conventional limited-information approach.

Related to this, one could explore issues about organizational governance and leadership. For example, tasking a leader with a particular objective could have a long-run transformational effect. But a leader may also create short-run unhappiness by de-motivating existing managers in her attempts to transform a prevailing culture. Careful monitoring would then be important, such that principals do not interpret poor short-term performance as the result of inability. There are many stories about leaders who attempt to change organizational cultures, but are edged out via protests by disgruntled insiders or complaints by short-run-profit-oriented owners. One could analyze such endogenous leadership selection in our framework.

It is possible to extend our framework in yet other ways. Hirschman (1970) famously emphasized three sources of organizational dynamics: exit, voice, and loyalty. While earlier analyses have highlighted exit versus voice, our analysis focuses on loyalty as embedded in social identity. But our setting has room for exit and voice as well. Exit could, for example, reflect organizations under stress hiring outside managers with different cultural convictions to bypass inside managers with a certain dysfunctional culture. Voice could, for example, reflect senior managers being allowed to vote over the organization’s mission.

Finally, this article asks how organizations adapt their design to endogenously changing values. We believe the idea of linking cultural and institutional change is a promising way of exploring societal dynamics in other contexts. In Besley and Persson (2019) , we study how evolving democratic values interact with reforms of democratic institutions by country leaders. More research should follow on the interplay between strategically chosen institutions and slow-moving cultural values. 9

Supplementary material is available at Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization online.

We abstract from the possibility of external recruitment by supposing that all upper-tier managers are internally recruited. External recruitment would be an interesting extension of the approach that we take. Part of the Online Appendix shows how we can also allow junior managers to put in effort.

Note that the interior solutions for d reflect the presence of the decentralization cost. With ϕ ( d ) = 0 ⁠ , we would have d ( 0 ) = 1 iff μ > π when θ = 0 and d ( 0 ) = 1 iff 1 − μ > π when θ = 1.

Note that when δ ( · ) is interior, then ∂ μ ^ ∂ π = − β δ μ ( μ ) + ( 1 − β ) δ 1 − μ ( 1 − μ ) β δ μ ( μ ) + ( 1 − β ) δ 1 − μ ( 1 − μ ) .

One interpretation of this would be where a firm hires and fires workers each period to avoid being entrapped by a particular workplace culture.

This logic is reminiscent of that in Vickers (1985) , where an oligopolistic firm seeking to maximize profits can raise profits by appointing a CEO with an objective to maximize sales as a way of committing to aggressive pricing behavior. In a classic paper, Rogoff (1985) studies strategic delegation in the context of central banking.

Suppose that ϕ ( z ) = z 1 + 1 η

with η ≤ 1 ⁠ . Then, 1 + ( 1 − μ − π ) η − η ( 1 − μ − π ) η − 1 ( 1 − μ ) = 1 + ( 1 − μ − π ) η [ 1 − η 1 − μ 1 − μ − π ] > 0

if η is small enough and likewise 1 + ( μ − π ) η − η ( μ − π ) η − 1 μ = 1 + ( 1 − μ − π ) η [ 1 − η μ μ − π ] > 0

if η is small enough.

We continue to assume that there are no contractual solutions around the problem since project choices (and identities) are non-verifiable.

An obvious extension would be to assume a distribution of u across managers. In this case, progressively higher leader charisma would smoothly raise the share of non-aligned managers that acted in the organization’s interest.

Persson and Tabellini (2021) provide an analytical survey of the emerging theoretical literature on interacting cultures and institutions.

We are grateful to Philippe Aghion, Roland Benabou, Maitreesh Ghatak, Bob Gibbons, Oliver Hart, Jay Lee, Rocco Macchiavello, John Hardman Moore, Jean Tirole, and Eric Verhoogen, as well as participants in meetings with the IOG program of the Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, the ERINN network, the Growth and Institutions program at Tsinghua University, the 2017 PEG Conference, the 2017 ESS conference, the 2018 conference on Culture, Institutions and Prosperity, the 2018 NBER Organizational Economics Working Group meeting, the 2018 Munich Lectures and an IIES seminar for helpful discussions and comments. We also thank the editor Andrea Prat and two anonymous referees for very useful comments.

Financial support from the European Research Council for the project ECOSOCPOL, and from the Swedish Research Council for a personal Research Chair is gratefully acknowledged.

Conflict of interest statement . None declared.

There are no new data associated with this article.

Acemoglu Daron.   2003 . “ Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics ,” 31   Journal of Comparative Economics   620 – 52 .

Google Scholar

Aghion Philippe , Tirole Jean . 1997 . “ Formal and Real Authority in Organizations ,” 105   Journal of Political Economy   1 – 29 .

Ahmad, Junaid, Shantayanan Devarajan, Stuti Khemani, and Shekhar Shah . 2005 . “Decentralization and Service Delivery,” Policy Research Working Paper 3603, The World Bank: Washington, D.C.

Akerlof George , Kranton Rachel . 2000 . “ Economics and Identity ,” 115   Quarterly Journal of Economics   715 – 53 .

Alesina Alberto , Giuliano Paola . 2015 . “ Culture and Institutions ,” 53   Journal of Economic Literature   898 – 944 .

Alger Ingela , Weibull Jörgen . 2013 . “ Homo Moralis—Preference Evolution under Incomplete Information and Assortative Matching ,” 81   Econometrica   2269 – 302 .

Alonso Ricardo , Dessein Wouter , Matouschek Niko . 2008 . “ When Does Coordination Require Centralization?,”   98   American Economic Review   145 – 79 .

Ashforth Blake E. , Mael Fred . 1989 . “ Social Identity Theory and the Organization ,” 14   Academy of Management Review   20 – 39 .

Bandiera Oriana , Hansen Stephen , Sadun Raffaella , Prat Andrea . 2016 . CEO Behavior and Firm Performance. Mimeo, LSE .

Benabou Roland.   2013 . “ Groupthink: Collective Delusions in Organizations and Markets ,” 80   Review of Economic Studies   429 – 62 .

Besley Timothy , Ghatak Maitreesh . 2005 . “ Competition and Incentives with Motivated Agents ,” 95   American Economic Review   616 – 36 .

Besley Timothy , Persson Torsten . 2019 . “ Democratic Values and Institutions ,” 1   American Economic Review Insights   59 – 76 .

Bidner Chris , Francois Patrick . 2011 . “ Cultivating Trust: Norms, Institutions and the Implications of Scale ,” 121   Economic Journal   1097 – 129 .

Bisin Alberto , Verdier Thierry . 2001 . “ The Economics of Cultural Transmission and the Dynamics of Preferences ,” 97   Journal of Economic Theory   298 – 319 .

Bisin Alberto , Verdier Thierry . 2011 . “Chapter 9—The Economics of Cultural Transmission and Socialization,” in Benhabib Jess , ed., Handbook of Social Economics , Vol. 1A . Amsterdam, Netherlands : Elsevier .

Google Preview

Bloom Nicholas , Sadun Raffaella , Van Reenen John . 2012 . “ The Organization of Firms across Countries ,” 127   Quarterly Journal of Economics   1663 – 705 .

Bloom Nicholas , Lemos Renata , Sadun Raffaella , Van Reenen John . 2015 . “ Does Management Matter in Schools?,”   125   Economic Journal   647 – 74 .

Bolton Patrick , Farrell Joseph . 1990 . “ Decentralization, Duplication, and Delay ,” 98   Journal of Political Economy   803 – 26 .

Boyd Robert , Richerson Peter . 1985 . Culture and the Evolutionary Process . Chicago, IL : University of Chicago Press .

Cavalli-Sforza Luigi L. , Feldman Marcus . 1981 . Cultural Transmission and Evolution . Princeton, NJ : Princeton University Press .

Coase Ronald H.   1937 . “ The Nature of the Firm ,” 4   Economica   386 – 405 .

Coase Ronald H.   1960 . “ The Problem of Social Cost ,” 3   Journal of Law and Economics   1 – 44 .

Cortada James W.   2018 . “ Change and Continuity at IBM: Key Themes in Histories of IBM ,” 92   Business History Review   117 – 48 .

Cyert Richard , March James G.   1963 . A Behavioral Theory of the Firm . Oxford, UK : Wiley-Blackwell .

Dessein Wouter.   2002 . “ Authority and Communication in Organizations ,” 69   Review of Economic Studies   811 – 38 .

Dessein Wouter , Prat Andrea . 2017 . “ Organizational Capital, Corporate Leadership, and Firm Dynamics .” Columbia Business School Research Paper No. 17 – 89 .

Dessi Roberta.   2008 . “ Collective Memory, Cultural Transmission and Investments ,” 98   American Economic Review   534 – 60 .

Gibbons Robert , Henderson Rebecca . 2012 . “What Do Managers Do? Exploring Persistent Performance Differences among Seemingly Similar Enterprises,” in Gibbons Robert , Roberts D. John , eds., Handbook of Organizational Economics . Princeton, NJ : Princeton University Press .

Greif Avner.   1994 . “ Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Theoretical and Historical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies ,” 102   Journal of Political Economy   912 – 950 .

Grossman Sanford , Hart Oliver D.   1986 . “ The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration ,” 94   Journal of Political Economy   691 – 719 .

Guiso Luigi , Sapienza Paola , Zingales Luigi . 2006 . “ Does Culture Affect Economic Outcomes?,”   20   Journal of Economic Perspectives   23 – 48 .

Guiso Luigi , Sapienza Paola , Zingales Luigi . 2013 . “ The Values of Corporate Culture ,” 117   Journal of Financial Economics   20 – 36 .

Güth Werner , Yaari Menahem E.   1992 . “Explaining Reciprocal Behavior in Simple Strategic Games: An Evolutionary Approach,” in Witt Ulrich , ed., Explaining Process and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary Economics . Ann Arbor, MI : University of Michigan Press .

Güth Werner.   1995 . “ An Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Cooperative Behavior by Reciprocal Incentives ,” 24   International Journal of Game Theory   323 – 44 .

Hart Oliver D. , Holmström Bengt . 2010 . “ A Theory of Firm Scope ,” 125   Quarterly Journal of Economics   483 – 513 .

Hirschman Albert O.   1970 . Exit, Voice and Loyalty . Cambridge, MA : Harvard University Press .

Hofstede Geert.   1984 . Culture’s Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions and Organizations across Nations . New York, NY : Sage Publications .

Hofstede Geert , Hofstede Gert Jan , Minkov Michael . 2010 . Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind . 3rd ed.   New York, NY : McGraw Hill .

Honig Daniel.   2018 . Navigation by Judgement: Why and When Top Down Management of Foreign Aid Doesn’t Work . Oxford, UK : Oxford University Press .

Inglehart Ronald , Basanez Miguel , Diez-Medrano Jaime , Halman Loek , Luijkx Ruud (eds.). 2004 . Human Beliefs and Values: A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook Based on the 1999–2002 Values Surveys . Mexico City : Siglo XXI .

Kovach Robert.   2017 . How Tribalism Hurts Companies, and What to Do About It. Harvard Business Review . Available at https://hbr.org/2017/07/how-tribalism-hurts-companies-and-what-to-do-about-it

Kreps David M.   1990 . “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” in Alt James , Shepsle Kenneth A. , eds., Perspectives on Positive Political Economy , Cambridge, UK : Cambridge University Press .

Lazear Edward P.   1995 . “Corporate Culture and the Diffusion of Values,” in Siebert Horst , ed., Trends in Business, Organization . Tübingen, Germany : J.C.B .

Mills D. Quinn.   1996 . “ The Decline and Rise of IBM ,” 37   Sloan Management Review   78 – 82 .

Persson Torsten , Tabellini Guido . 2021 . “Chapter 15—Culture, Institutions, and Policy,” in Bisin Alberto , Federico Giovanni , eds., Handbook of Historical Economics , Amsterdam, NL : Elsevier .

Peters Tom , Waterman Robert H. Jr . 1982 . Search of Excellence: Lessons from America’s Best-Run Companies . London, UK : Harper Collins .

Rantakari Heikki.   2008 . “ Governing Adaptation ,” 75   Review of Economic Studies   1257 – 85 .

Rantakari Heikki.   2012 . “ Employee Initiative and Managerial Control ,” 4   American Economic Journal: Microeconomics   171 – 211 .

Rogoff Kenneth.   1985 . “ The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target ,” 100   Quarterly Journal of Economics   1169 – 89 .

Sandholm William H.   2010 . Population Games and Evolutionary Dynamics . Cambridge, MA : MIT Press .

Schein Edgar H.   1990 . “ Organizational Culture ,” 45   American Psychologist   109 – 19 .

Tajfel Henri.   1974 . “ Social Identity and Intergroup Behaviour ,” 13   Social Science Information   65 – 93 .

Teece David , Pisano Gary , Shuen Amy . 1997 . “ Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management ,” 18   Strategic Management Journal   509 – 33 .

Tirole Jean.   1996 . “ A Theory of Collective Reputations (with Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality) ,” 63   Review of Economic Studies   1 – 22 .

Van den Steen Eric.   2010a . “ Culture Clash: The Costs and Benefits of Homogeneity ,” 56   Management Science   1718 – 38 .

Van den Steen Eric.   2010b . “ On the Origin of Shared Beliefs (and Corporate Culture) ,” 41   Rand Journal of Economics   617 – 48 .

Vickers John.   1985 . “ Delegation and the Theory of the Firm ,” 95   Economic Journal , 138 – 47 .

Weber Max.   1922 . “The Nature of Charismatic Authority and Its Routinization,” in Anderson A. R. , Parsons, eds Talcott ., Theory of Social and Economic Organization [1947 transl.]. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Whyte William H.   1956 . The Organization Man . New York, NY : Simon & Schuster .

Williamson Oliver E.   1979 . “ Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations ,” 22   Journal of Law and Economics   233 – 61 .

Wilson James Q.   1989 . Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It . New York, NY : Basic Books .

Supplementary data

Month: Total Views:
October 2022 66
November 2022 243
December 2022 144
January 2023 195
February 2023 151
March 2023 142
April 2023 173
May 2023 158
June 2023 169
July 2023 154
August 2023 164
September 2023 137
October 2023 166
November 2023 191
December 2023 150
January 2024 209
February 2024 259
March 2024 355
April 2024 485
May 2024 493
June 2024 617

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to your Library

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1465-7341
  • Print ISSN 8756-6222
  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Institutional account management
  • Rights and permissions
  • Get help with access
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Waiting for answer This question has not been answered yet. You can hire a professional tutor to get the answer.

Define and describe the concept of Organization Development, show how it operates, and describe the role of action research in strengthening an organization’s structure, culture, and processes. Streng

Define and describe the concept of Organization Development, show how it operates, and describe the role of action research in strengthening an organization’s structure, culture, and processes. Strengthen your argument by choosing ONE of the seven (in the attached file) illustrations cited in Chapter One that best fits your workplace. You will support your choice by giving examples from your workplace that closely resemble the Illustration you have chosen.

Submission Instructions:

  • The paper is to be clear and concise and students will lose points for improper grammar, punctuation, and misspelling.
  • The paper should be formatted per the current APA and 3-5 pages in length, excluding the title and reference page. Incorporate a minimum of 5 current (published within the last five years) scholarly journal articles or primary legal sources (statutes, court opinions) within your work.
  • This assignment is assessed through Turnitin.

GET YOUR EXPERT ANSWER ON STUDYDADDY

Post your own question and get a custom answer

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  • Q: I would like help completing my essay for English 103. The essay needs to describe how perception management is used to cover up reality. The topic I chose was police brutality and I have already star
  • Q: Most research projects include a literature review to determine what knowledge exists on the subject under study and to develop the theoretical framework that will be used in the study. The literature
  • Q: HRMT 301 Assignment 1 Due: After completion of Lessons 1–4 Credit weight: 25% of your final grade Expectations: 500–750 words Summary: Conducting a job analysis Format Prepare your assignment in a f H
  • Q: NP paper
  • Q: Purpose -The purpose of this assignment is to demonstrate an understanding of the Army Health System (AHS). Background Information - Army Health System support is provided across the competition con
  • Q: Organizational creativity and innovation have proven to be challenging concepts to measure. There is not a particular output that indicates organizational levels of innovation. To flourish, innovation

Have a similar question?

Continue to edit or attach image(s).

  • Group Discussion - 1 hour ago
  • Human Resource - Reflection 1 hour ago
  • S01 Introduction to Psychology I Directions: Be... 1 hour ago
  • This week, you will submit the second project... 1 hour ago
  • Assessment Description How can multicultural co... 1 hour ago

Applied Sciences

Architecture and Design

Art & Design

Article Writing

Business & Finance

Communications

Computer Science

Engineering

Environmental Science

Foreign Languages

Health & Medical

HR Management

Information Systems

Numerical Analysis

Political Science

Precalculus

Programming

Social Science

Times Nursing

1-3 JOURNAL: ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURE AND CULTURE

by ella | Apr 13, 2024 | Uncategorized

1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure And Culture

by ella | Apr 11, 2024 | Health

College
Business
Other(not listed)
1 Page(s)/275 words
1
APA
Double Spacing
Order a plagiarism free paper today !

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  • FULL DISCUSSION GUIDE ON NEUROPATHIC PAIN

Order a similar assignment, and have writers from our team of experts write it for you, guaranteeing you an A

Order Solution Now

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  Information Impact: Journal of Information and Knowledge Management Journal / Information Impact: Journal of Information and Knowledge Management / Vol. 15 No. 1 (2024) / Articles (function() { function async_load(){ var s = document.createElement('script'); s.type = 'text/javascript'; s.async = true; var theUrl = 'https://www.journalquality.info/journalquality/ratings/2406-www-ajol-info-iijikm'; s.src = theUrl + ( theUrl.indexOf("?") >= 0 ? "&" : "?") + 'ref=' + encodeURIComponent(window.location.href); var embedder = document.getElementById('jpps-embedder-ajol-iijikm'); embedder.parentNode.insertBefore(s, embedder); } if (window.attachEvent) window.attachEvent('onload', async_load); else window.addEventListener('load', async_load, false); })();  

Article sidebar.

Open Access

Article Details

Creative Commons License

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License .

The journal not only allows the authors to hold the copyright without restrictions, the authors also retain the full publishing right without restrictions.| ©; 2017 ISSN: 2141 - 4297 (print) ISSN: 2360 - 994X (e-version) 

Main Article Content

Organizational culture and turnover intention of librarians in southern nigeria, omobolanle seri fasola, sunday olanrewaju popoola.

This study sets out to investigate the relationship between organisational culture of university libraries and turnover intention of  librarians in private universities in southern Nigerian. Type of culture, bond that binds, organisational structure and leadership style were  the constructs of organisational culture investigated. The research design employed is the survey of the correlational type. The  population are all the librarians in these private university libraries making a total of 308. Census sampling technique was used to study  all of the librarians in the universities. The questionnaire was the instrument of data collection. Data collection was done by physically  administering the questionnaire to the respondents with the help of three research assistants over a four-week period. Total returned  questionnaire found usable was 289. Data from the research questions was analysed using frequency count and simple statistics while  the hypothesis posed was tested using Pearson Product Moment Correlation (PPMC). Findings revealed that the predominant culture of  the private universities studies is the Adhocracy culture with mean of ( x̄ = 15.61, SD = 4.60). Turnover intention of librarians was also  shown to be high with mean of (x̄ = 46.46, SD = 5.87). organisational structure was controlled and structures with a mean of ( x̄ =3.14;  SD=0.60); predominant leadership style was found to be transformational ( x̄=3.04; SD=0.64) while the bonds that holds was ( x̄ =3.12;  SD=0.50). It is recommended that library management of private universities should formulate policies that enhance bonding, structure,   leadership and culture type in order to reduce turnover intention and stem actual turnover.

AJOL is a Non Profit Organisation that cannot function without donations. AJOL and the millions of African and international researchers who rely on our free services are deeply grateful for your contribution. AJOL is annually audited and was also independently assessed in 2019 by E&Y.

Your donation is guaranteed to directly contribute to Africans sharing their research output with a global readership.

  • For annual AJOL Supporter contributions, please view our Supporters page.

Journal Identifiers

1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

IMAGES

  1. 1-3 Journal Organizatonal structure and culture.docx

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  2. SOLUTION: Unit 12 organizational structure and culture assignment

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  3. 1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  4. 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  5. 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

  6. Week 1 Journal.docx

    1 3 journal organizational structure and culture assignment

VIDEO

  1. BT21303(Section 1) Organizational Behaviour Group Assignment

  2. Dimensions of Organizational Culture

  3. Leadership: Cultivating Organizational Effectiveness, Segment 3

  4. Organizational Structure and Design

  5. Simple Junk Journal Intro Layout / Creative Journal / Easy Scrapbooking / Using a Junk Journal

  6. Management Chapter 9: Organizational Structure and Design

COMMENTS

  1. 1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture

    1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture after reading this weeks discussion and the readings from the module the view on the organization chose has. Skip to document. University; ... 4-1 Assignment- Internal Controls. Financial Accounting 91% (11) 6. 5-2 Milestone Three- Letter to Stakeholders. Healthcare Economics 100% (4) 3.

  2. OL-342 1-3 Journal Week 1

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Victoria Anderson May 2021. After reviewing and reading this week's assigned materials, I was able to see the better parts of my former organization, however, I would like to write this journal on a company that I aspire to work with one day.

  3. 1-3 Journal

    Lynn Pinkrah 3/16/ OL- Professor K Baker 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture After going through Module One, my viewpoint on my organization still stands. My job upholds their stance on following the rules and policies in place and values diversity within the workplace.

  4. 1-3 Journal.docx

    1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture After our reading and discussion, my views of organization's structure and culture have not changed. The discussions proved that an organization's structure and culture is very important to the success of each individual in the workplace. This is essential in identifying internal and external issues within the organization and correct them ...

  5. OL 342 Wk 1 Journal 1-3 Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    1-3 JOURNAL: ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURE AND CULTURE After this week's reading and discussion, share in a journal assignment whether and how your view of the organization reviewed within the Module One discussion topic changed. Note: I am having a problem finding the chapters in the book, not sure why. I did send you an e-mail but, in the meantime, I googled the organizational theories to have ...

  6. 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    Alessandra Nuzzo OL - 342 November 7 th , 2019 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture This week, though our assignments, I have gained so much insight on the organizational structure and culture, now I am able to have a better understanding on how small businesses can also be affected by this. The organizational theory that caught my eye the most was the theory of behavioral ...

  7. 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture

    1. 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Southern New Hampshire University Cynthia Worrell. 2. 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Since I finished Module 1, I have not experienced any shift in my perspective toward the company I currently work for.

  8. 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture

    1-3 Organizational Structure and Culture MY view of my Organization Lutheran Health Hospital has not changed at all since completing Module 1. My Current employer values diversity and adheres to the policy. Our recruitment team is up to date on the latest topics and is constantly recruiting on social media websites, internet, and job search sites like Indeed.

  9. 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture

    After this week's reading and discussion, share in a journal assignment whether and how your view of the organization reviewed within the Module One discussion topic changed. Are you able to better identify benefits among certain organizational theories? Explain the theory and the specific benefit(s) (e.g., employee satisfaction, diversity ...

  10. Theories of Organizational Culture

    Abstract. The notion that organizations may have specific cultures is found sprinkled in a vast array of publications on strategy and business policy, on organizational behaviour and theory. Although the absence of a solid theoretical grounding for the concept of organizational culture has been frequently lamented, little effort has been ...

  11. Assignment on Organizational Structure Culture

    1.1 Compare and contrast the structure and culture of the organization. Organizational structure refers to the norms, rules, policies formed by the company to achieve the objectives. Organizational Culture includes the value, behaviour and attitudes of the employees. Both of these are equally important for the success of the organization.

  12. 1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    View Essay - 1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture.docx from OL 342 at Southern New Hampshire University. Sekina Ray Instructor John Murphy Organizational Behavior 03/11/2018 ORGANIZATION ... Sekina Ray Instructor John Murphy Organizational Behavior 03/11/2018 ORGANIZATION BEHAVIOR JOURNAL ASSIGNMENT View of the organization.

  13. 1 3 journal organizational structure culture

    The organization definitely offered. After reviewing and completion of Module one, my current view and opinion on what Istated regarding the Nonprofit organization still stands. The organization definitely offered. Post a Question. Provide details on what you need help with along with a budget and time limit. ...

  14. Solved Important components of the organizing facet of the

    Question: Important components of the organizing facet of the P-O-L-C framework are organizational structure and culture. Change is inevitable in any company, and managers who understand how to manage change within their organizational structure and culture will be more successful with implementing and sustaining change.

  15. 1-3 Journal-Organizational Structure and Culture

    IHP420 Week 3 Assignment; IHP 420 Milestone ONE - Jessica Jackson; Grade: A- - Module 4 - Claims of Negligence - 4-3 Case Study: Claims of Negligence ... Preview text. Monica S. Nelson 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure Culture OL-342-H4231 Organizational Behavior 22EW July 2022. After this week's reading and discussion, I examine a previous ...

  16. Organizational Culture And Structure Sample Written Assignments and Samples

    Self help samples and Organizational Culture And Structure sample assignments to help you approach your assignments easily. Organizational Culture And Structure Academic essays, reports, case studies, literature reviews and more. Get the guidance to plan and write great Organizational Culture And Structure assignments.

  17. Organizational dynamics: culture, design, and performance

    3.5 Organizational culture. We refer to μ t —the share of identity-0 managers at t—as the organization's culture. In state θ = 0, the leader's preferences align with those of type τ = 0 managers, but clash with preferences of type τ = 1 managers, and vice versa in state θ = 1.

  18. 1 3 journal organizational structure and cultural.docx

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Jamie Black 05/09/2020 After this week's discussion, I have a better understanding on an organizational structure and culture. With the understanding that small businesses can also be affected by the structural influences. Employee satisfaction is a major organizational theory can make or break a business/company.

  19. 1-3 Journal Organizational Structure and Culture

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Dina Hamad January 8, 2022. My opinion of my current organization hasn't changed since completing Module 1. My current employer values diversity and adheres to policy. Our recruitment team is up to date on the latest topics and is constantly recruiting on social media websites.

  20. Define and describe the concept of Organization Development, show how

    Define and describe the concept of Organization Development, show how it operates, and describe the role of action research in strengthening an organization's structure, culture, and processes. Strengthen your argument by choosing ONE of the seven (in the attached file) illustrations cited in Chapter One that best fits your workplace.

  21. 1-3 Journal- Organizational Structure and Culture.docx

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture I personally feel that the employees cannot create the culture of the company. It is up to the employer. When it comes to people working for your company you have to leave the impression that you're actually a good company to work for. For example, the racial environment that exist in some companies are created by what the owner allows.

  22. 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure And Culture by ella | Apr 11, 2024 | Health After this week's reading and discussion, share in a journal assignment whether and how your view of the organization reviewed within the Module One discussion topic changed. Are you able to better identify benefits among certain organizational theories? Explain the theory

  23. 1-3 Journal-Organizational Structure and Culture

    2-2 Journal: Workplace Behaviors Destiny Williams 1 1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Destiny L. Williams Southern New Hampshire University Organizational Behavior (OL-342-H6953) Professor Stacy Vearil 07 JULY 2023 2-2 Journal: Workplace Behaviors Destiny Williams 2

  24. Organizational Culture and Turnover Intention of Librarians in Southern

    This study sets out to investigate the relationship between organisational culture of university libraries and turnover intention of librarians in private universities in southern Nigerian. Type of culture, bond that binds, organisational structure and leadership style were the constructs of organisational culture investigated. The research design employed is the survey of the correlational type.

  25. Organizational Structure and Culture 3 Journal 1.docx

    1-3 Journal: Organizational Structure and Culture Ol-342-T2693 Organizational behavior Maressa Montes De Oca 11/3/2018 assignments on time, it is affecting the culture within our department amongst current staff. As a solution to this problem, we spoke to this employee, expressing our feelings in a respectable way that would not offend the staff. ...